On 16 July, as was widely reported, China announced
very strong economic growth in the first half of 2009. GDP was up 7.1%
year on year for the six months to June. Growth was 7.9% for the second
quarter of 2009 compared to the same period in 2008.
Economic
acceleration was evident as China's year on year growth rose from 6.1%
in the first quarter to 7.9% in the second. Industrial production in
June was up 10.7% year on year. In terms of annualised quarter on
quarter growth, official figures for which China does not publish as it
considers its data on seasonable adjustments are not yet sufficiently
accurate, the Wall Street Journal
notes private economist estimates of 15% annualised GDP growth in the
second quarter.It therefore appears highly likely China will hit its
8% annual growth target this year.
Despite this rapid growth there was
no sign of inflationary pressures in consumer or output prices due to overheating
- on the contrary year on year consumer prices in June were down 1.7%
and the producer prices declined by 7.8%.
These are evidently stellar
figures in the context of the international financial crisis - by far
the best results of any major economy. They also cast
clear light on the debate that has been taking place internationally on
the correctness, or otherwise, of the policies being pursued by China
in dealing with the international financial crisis. Such first half GDP
figures evidently indicate great success, and countries pursuing
objectively guided policies would study China to
see carefully what lessons could be learned from this.
This is particularly important as China is not pursuing a course based on running a large budget deficit. Such policies, which are generally mistakenly referred to as
'Keynesian' in the US and Europe, are dominant in those countries' recovery
packages - 'mistakenly' because Keynes own views were focused on
monetary economics, and based on the priority to reduce interest rates
by measures such as quantitative easing, not on expansion of budget
deficits, as writers such as Turner and Tily rightly point out. A policy of meeting the financial crisis through large budget
deficits might be correct, as Paul Krugman argues, or it may be incorrect. but it is not actually a 'Keynesian' policy in the sense of being the one advocated by Keynes.
Contrary to some mistaken claims
in the financial media, China's stimulus package is, however, not based on a
large budget deficit. This is clearly confirmed by the figures. China's deficit is projected to expand this year
but only modestly, from balance to a deficit of 3% of GDP.
China's
stimulus package is instead focused on two measures. The first is
direct methods to raise, that is control, investment - thereby avoiding
the precipitate fall in investment which is the driving force of an economic downturn.
The largest part of China's $585 billion stimulus package is going into urban fixed investment
which rose 33.5% year on year in the first half of 2009 and 35.3% in
the year to June. As, in the same period, producer prices were falling
sharply it is likely that the real increase in investment in fixed
assets approached 40%. China is able to achieve this due to its large
state company sector which can be issued with 'administrative'
instructions to increase investment, thereby countering any downturn.
The second part of the stimulus package is expansion of bank lending. M2 was up in China by 28.5% year on year in June with bank lending rising by RMB 1.5 trillion ($220 billion) in June and RMB 7.37 trillion ($1.1 trillion) in the first half
of 2009. The fact that China's banks are state owned allows them to be
instructed to increase lending - whereas in the US and Europe only indirect, so
far relatively ineffective, methods can be used to attempt to
persuade banks to counter-cyclically expand their lending.
This
combination
of direct measures to expand investment and rapid increase
in bank lending explains the success of the stimulus package and
therefore China's rapid economic growth in the first half of the year.
This model is
evidently quite different to, and far more successful, than the
policies based on large scale budget deficits being pursued in the US
and Europe.
A number of non-Chinese commentators have accurately judged that the Chinese stimulus package will be successful
- the most prominent probably being Jim O'Neill,
Goldman Sach's chief economist. In contrast theorists that China is
'oversaving', and must change its economic model, who are given
frequent extensive coverage in sections of the the media, such as Martin Wolf of the Financial Times and Michael Pettis,
have been proved inaccurate.
It would be
hoped that as economic theory has not led writers such as Wolf and
Pettis to change their analysis facts might now lead to an acknowledgement
their analysis is wrong. As, however, they have maintained views which
are false from the point of view of economic analysis, and from the
point of view of economic facts, for many years it is probably unlikely
there will be any change in light of the latest data. Indeed Pettis in
his latest post, commenting on China's GDP figures bizarrely, in the light of the facts,
claims: 'I think China will be among the last countries to escape from
the effects of the global crisis,' This is roughly the economic
equivalent of continuing to believe that the world is flat despite the
fact that all evidence shows it is round.
Fortunately for the
health both of China's and the world economies the Chinese authorities
have continued to pursue their own policies and ignore such advice from
outside. The latest GDP data confirms just how right they were to do so.